Wednesday 31 December 2014

31 December 2014: Greece, what now?

I´m being asked what I think about the current economic situation in Greece following the call for snap elections (to take place on 25 January 2015).

Simple question, simple answer: I think the same I thought/wrote in January 2014. This:

With a public debt to GDP ratio of 175% (public debt around Eur 320bn), Greece's debt burden is unsustainable. A debt restructuring unavoidable.

Given that (i) the Troika (EU, ECB, IMF) is not willing to restructure Greek debt and (ii) Greece will not be able to achieve any reasonable economic growth under such a heavy debt burden, social and political turmoil is unavoidable. The left-wing Syriza party, led by Alexis Tsipras, will win the next early general elections - taking place in 2015, the latest -, force a debt restructuring, impose capital controls, nationalise the entire banking system and lead Greece out of the Euro. Private investors, starting with Greek government bondholders, will suffer heavy losses. But leaving the Euro is the right thing to do: Greece has no chance to regain its competitiveness staying in the Eurozone. The Greek exit in turn will trigger Portugal and Spain's exit from the Euro. Possibly even Italy's. It will mark the beginning of the end of the Euro project.

This, in short, is the prevalent view among many economists, investors, leading newspapers and opinion makers. However, sometimes perception and reality are far, far apart. This is one of those notable occasions. This is why:

1. The Greek public debt burden is undoubtedly very high. But 85% of it is held by the Troika: EU, 65%; ECB, 10%; IMF, 10%. Meaning: a debt restructuring doesn't require any private sector involvement. The debt restructuring can be borne by official creditors alone.

2. There is no incentive to involve the private sector in a public debt restructuring. Why scare off private investors - who are so very much needed for a jump in investment, structural change in Greek's productive structure (via FDI) and economic growth - when (i) they only hold 15% of the total Greek public debt (ii) some of them have just put Greece back on their radar screen, (iii) the first Greek public debt restructuring back in 2011 was borne by private investors and (iv) it is much easier to sit at a table and negotiate with three creditors (EU, ECB and IMF) than with hundreds of them (private investors). Therefore, even if Syriza wins the next general elections don't expect any losses for private investors in Greek debt. Alexis Tsipras may be a populist politician, but he is not mad. He knows too well that foreign investment (and especially FDI) is needed to turn the Greek economy around and create the foundations for sustainable economic growth.

3. The 65% of public debt held by the EU had initially (2010) a 7-year maturity. It paid an interest rate of 3M Euribor +5.5%. Since then maturities have been extended and interest rates cut, leading to the following figures at the end of December 2013:

- The debt maturity is 31 years

- The interest rate on 15% out of the 65% (EU bilateral loans - Greek loan facility (GLF) - as the EU rescue fund EFSF / EFSM / ESM was not yet in place in 2010) is 3M Euribor + 0.5%

- The interest rate on the remaining 50% out of the 65% is 3M Euribor + 1.5%. More importantly, interest payments on these loans (already conceded by the EFSF) were deferred for 10 years. No interest payments are due until November 2022

Sounds good? It gets even better: in November 2012, the EU agreed to transfer every year to the Greek government the profits made by the ECB with its securities market programme (SMP) accruing to the Greek central bank. In 2013, this amounted to Eur 1.5bn. The total interest payments to the Troika were Eur 1.7bn (less than 1% of Greek GDP)

4. Currently, total interest payments on Greek public debt account (including the deferred interest payments on EFSF loans) for 3.5% of the country's GDP. This compares with 2% for Germany; 3.2% for Spain; 4.1% for Portugal; 4.3% for Ireland; 5.2% for Italy.

By the way, did the Euro make everything worse? No. At the end of 1998 (just before the Euro was launched), Greek interest payments on public debt accounted for 7.4% of GDP. For Italy, the figure was 6.1%; Portugal, 3.8%; Spain, 3.3%; Ireland, 2.2%. Except for Ireland, the lower interest rates post-Euro (and generous bail-out financing terms for Greece, Portugal and Ireland) more than offset the currently (much) higher levels of public debt.

In short: contrary to common wisdom it is not true that the Troika, led by the EU, is not willing to restructure Greece's public debt. A soft and silent Greek public debt restructuring has been under way for the past 2 years. Simply neither the EU (and especially Germany) nor Greece have been advertising it very loudly for obvious political reasons. But being silent doesn't mean being non-existent.

Is there anything missing for the Greek debt restructuring to be completed? Maybe. Namely:

a) Extending the maturities of ECB held bonds and IMF loans to over 30 years and reduce interest rates to 3M Euribor + 50bps (GLF terms) on all debt held by the Troika? No problem.

The IMF wants to get out of Greece and its money back at the end of 2016. Mr. Schäuble, the German finance minister, said during the German election campaign in the summer 2013, that Greece would need a third and last rescue package of Eur 50bn to Eur 60bn by the end of 2016. The IMF loans and ECB held bonds amount on aggregate to roughly Eur 60bn. What a coincidence, isn't it?

With the ESM replacing the IMF and ECB as creditor, consider the debt maturity extension and lowering of interest rates to 3M Euribor + 50bps (on the entire official sector held Greek public debt) a done deal. Obviously all this will be made conditional to the country continuing to implement the famous structural reforms. And obviously with the Greek government trying to soften down conditionality as much as possible while the EU trying to keep the pressure high at all times. But in the end an agreement will be reached. As usual.*

b) Extending debt maturities to 50 years for a sustainable level of public debt to be achieved? Doable, if needed.

Or is it reasonable to expect that after having extended debt maturities from 7 to over 30 years over the past 2 years, and all the effort made to stabilize the financial situation in Greece and the EU periphery, the EU will not concede Greece such a debt extension if needed? The answer can only be a resounding "no".

And now the important question: what will be the impact of (i) extending maturities to 30 years on all Greek public debt held by the Troika (remember: this means that none of this debt has to be refinanced for 30 years) and (ii) lower interest rates to a level such that Greece will be able to generate a primary surplus to pay the interests on all its public debt (held by the Troika and private investors)?

- Assuming a nominal annual growth rate of 4% over a 30 year period (30 years is a long, long time) - and with private sector held debt as a % of GDP remaining constant - Greek public debt would reach 70% of GDP by 2043

- In case of a debt maturity extension to 50 years, Greek public debt as a % of GDP would reach 45% in 2063

We can discuss all these assumptions and results. But that would be missing the point of the whole exercise. The point is to show that (i) by eliminating the refinancing needs / refinancing risk on public debt held by the official sector for 30 (or 50) years and (ii) continuing to lower interest rates to enable Greece to fully cover its interest payments with a modest primary public budget surplus, the Troika (read EU) is effectively restructuring slowly, surely and silently Greece's public debt.

The most interesting of all is that this gigantic public debt restructuring is about to make the country the best GIPS in terms of balance sheet quality. Sounds lunacy? Can't after all the same soft and silent debt restructuring strategy be followed for other countries, like Portugal, Ireland and Spain?

Yes and no. It can be done. It will be done. However, the impact will be more limited: Portugal's public debt is around 120% of GDP, but "just" 45% of it is held by the Troika; for Ireland's the numbers are 105% and 40%, respectively; for Spain 90% and less than 5%.

More importantly, Greece's comparative advantage doesn't lie on its public sector balance sheet. The key to understand why Greece is about to become the GIPS best quality balance sheet is to look at countries' private debt levels. The following chart makes things clear (note: the data is from Dec 2010, but no meaningful changes occurred in private debt levels. Only in public debt, which increased in all depicted countries. Reason for which I relieved myself from the pain of updating the chart with the most recent BIS data):

      Source: BIS / Casey Research

No, there is no mistake in the chart. And no, it's not an illusion. Your eye-sight is just doing fine: Greece is the EU country with the lowest level of private debt (household and corporate) as a % of GDP. Lower than Italy. Lower than Austria. Lower than Germany. With the public debt restructuring under way, Greece is about to become the EU country with the cleanest aggregate balance sheet (public + private). Surprise, surprise.

What about external competitiveness? Isn't Greece's lack of competitiveness at the root of its debt problems? Yes, it is. And doesn't this mean that an Euro exit is the only realistic way for the loss of competitiveness to be restored? No, it doesn't.

The loss of competitiveness has in fact been restored over the past three years. Look for yourself to what happened to Greek unit labour costs....

      Source: OECD

....and to put Greece's unit labour costs (ULC) evolution in perspective, here are two more charts:

      Source: Eurostat, ECB, Ameco, Tortus Capital

      Source: Eurostat, ECB, Ameco, Tortus Capital

Not bad at all, isn't it? And yes, Greece is now (end 2013) running a small current account surplus. Furthermore, with more than 2/3 of the Greek public supporting the Euro, exiting the Eurozone is definitely not an option any Greek politician is going to pursue.

Finally, could Mr. Tsipras force a debt haircut if he comes to power? Now that Greece is running a current account surplus - and not dependent on external financing anymore to pay for its imports - as well as a primary public budget surplus, he certainly could declare default and force a restructuring of the Troika (and especially EU) loans. From a pure financial point of view, it wouldn't make much sense: even if he obtained a 50% haircut on the EU held debt, and Greece financed itself in the market at a 4% interest rate for 10-year maturities afterwards, the Greek government would pay more in interests than it is paying now (and as much as it would pay without the 10-year interest deferral on EFSF loans). From a political point of view it might however be an attractive option: he would be deemed the national hero that liberated the Greek people from their suffocating debt burden.

Then again, in practical economic terms an haircut would only make visible and loud what is currently hidden and silent: a massive debt relief for the Greek government is taking place.

Sunday 23 November 2014

Climate change: it's not about believing. It's about risk management

There are a few things we know. And a few things we don't know. This applies to many domains in life, including climate change.

This is what we know about climate change:

1. The amount of CO2 in the atmosphere has increased exponentially since the beginning of the industrial revolution in 1760. This is man-made

2. The world's average temperature has risen with the increase of CO2 in the atmosphere. There is a clear and strong correlation between the two

Then there are a few things we don't know:

A. Is correlation also causation? From a pure static point of view, yes: we know that everything else being constant, the increase in CO2's concentration in the atmosphere strengthens the greenhouse effect and leads to a rise in average temperatures. From a dynamic point of view, we don't know with absolute certainty. And the reason is that we don't fully understand how the different gases in the atmosphere, and the different parts of the complex climate system, interact with each other. Is the atmosphere, the climate system as a whole, able to adapt to CO2's concentration increase and offset it? Does the atmosphere have an embedded bail-out mechanism that will prevent a dangerous rise in global temperatures in response to an increase in CO2 concentration in the atmosphere and rescue us all from the potential adverse consequences?

B. How comes that CO2's concentration in the atmosphere has continued to increase exponentially over the past 15 years while global temperatures remained flat?

Source: IPCC Fifth Assessment Synthesis Report, October 2014

The latter could lead us to think that standard climate models are flawed and we don't need to worry about climate change and CO2 emissions after all. Then again, absence of evidence doesn't mean that there is evidence of absence. It may just be the case that for some reason, that we don't fully understand yet, the climate system has been able to offset temporarily the increase in CO2 emissions. However, as CO2's concentration in the atmosphere continues to increase the "offset mechanism" may just break down at some point and a reversion to the trend of rising temperatures occur.

Where does all this leave us? There is no absolute certainty that there is man-made climate change, but there is a non-negligible probability that it is occurring. No negligible probability means a high enough probability for the US' National Academy of Sciences and the UK's Royal Society to claim in February 2014 that with near certainty man-made climate change is happening (here the link). They can be both wrong but since there is no one out there with more knowledge and authority to make such a claim than these two institutions (sorry guys, but this is not an ideological discussion), this means that we are facing a risk management problem. And that we can end up making two types of mistakes: we can assume that there is man-made climate change and then there isn't (error type I) or we can assume that there isn't man-made climate change and then there is (error type II). Which of the two errors would have the most devastating consequences for humanity?

If we commit error type I, we will end up spending money unnecessarily in accelerating the development of renewable energy technologies; more energetically efficient buildings, cars and electronic devices; more integrated and efficient mass transport systems - all with the aim to bring annual CO2 emissions down and towards a path consistent (at least 67% probability) with a 2°C average rise in global temperatures by 2100 relative to the 1850-1900 average (the maximum temperature increase climate scientists tend to agree is consistent with a very limited adverse impact on the environment). If we start to tackle the problem right now, it will cost us 1% to 4% of annual global GDP by 2050 (according to IPCC's 2014 Report). It will be an inefficient use of resources, sure. But it is not that we will get nothing in return. We will: better quality of air, less polluted rivers, less noisy traffic, cleaner and greener cities. A more beautiful world. There are worse ways to squander money (by the way, given that the world economy is growing, and has the potential to continue to grow, at 3.5% - 4% annually, it means that we would need to wait until 2051 to be as rich as without pursuing a "green agenda" we would already be in.....2050)

If we commit error type II, we will end up facing more frequent and severe floodings, draughts, loss of biodiversity and valuable ecosystems, shortages of potable water and food, disease outbreaks, mass migration of populations and related border conflicts, political instability, possibly wars. This may even be just a tail risk. But it is one with massive negative consequences. And the cost of hedging against it is low.

We can further argue, as Richard Tol from Sussex University does, that global warming's positive consequences over the past century have actually more than offset the negative ones: more deaths due to heat waves were more than offset by less deaths due to cold waves; the increase in atmospheric concentration of CO2, which is a powerful fertiliser, has increased global agricultural yields. And the positive effects are likely to continue to offset the negative ones for the coming decades, as long as the global temperature doesn't increase by more than 2°C, or even 3°C, relative to the 1850-1900 average, which on current trends (ignoring the last 15 years potential outlier) shouldn't happen before 2080 anyway (more than a 50% chance). Then again, even if all this was true what would be the geographic distributional effects of it? We would have a higher global agricultural production as part of Siberia's territory became highly productive agricultural land. But at the same time part of Africa and Southern Europe's agricultural land would become less fertile. Do we really want to become dependent on food from "good global citizen" Russia? It may even happen that by 2080 Russia does become an exemplary global citizen. Or not. Furthermore, what will we do after 2080 if global temperatures are then 3% above the 1850-1900 average? And rising.

The sensible conclusion can only be one: we can discuss if we should allocate scarce resources to mitigate a potentially dangerous rise in global temperatures by cutting CO2 emissions or simply to adapt to its consequences (a la Bjorn Lomborg, which basically means to help poor countries getting much richer). Or a combination of both. We can, and should, also discuss if the best way to cut CO2 emissions is by attributing massive long-term subsidies to operators of inefficient renewable energy technology (I think it's not). Doing nothing however is clearly not an option.

Will we do what is needed? Yes, we will.

Because young generations count. And because a backward looking crystal ball says so.

No matter what University campus one visits today, there is no more popular and engaging topic among students then climate change. And there is an almost unanimous view that something needs to be done to mitigate it and adapt to its consequences. These boys and girls may be too young today to have a saying in world affairs. But excessive youth is a problem that time solves. They will be the future leaders of the world. And make it happen.

Then there is the German backward looking crystal ball. In the 1980s the green party entered the German parliament. They were considered outsiders and fringe. However, by making the green topic popular they forced the traditional parties to include it in their agendas. The "greenest" German Bundesland today is arguably Bavaria - it is also the most politically conservative. Since its 2011 federal state elections, the second most conservative, Badden-Württemberg, is run by a government coalition led by the....green party - following massive public protests about the environmental impact of a railway project that the incumbent government at the time, led by the conservative party (CDU) in power since 1953, didn't address effectively. What does this tell us? In the XXI century, citizens do care about green. And governments can't afford to ignore it.

So, dear worries about climate change: chill out. Youth counts. Beauty counts. Green is about to become mainstream.

Everything is under control.

Monday 8 September 2014

Draghinomics ABS is big. Very BIG!

ECB's asset-backed securities purchase programme (ABS PP), with underlying assets consisting of loans to the Euro-area non-financial private sector (i.e. corporates), announced by Mario Draghi on Thursday was received with subdued enthusiasm by commentators and financial markets alike.

The widespread perception is that it is a step in the right direction in order to unblock credit flows to Eurozone's private corporate sector, especially small and mid-sized enterprises (SME) in EU's periphery that have no direct access to credit markets and rely entirely on bank financing. However, the programme is too small to have any meaningful economic impact: the total stock of SME ABS outstanding is approx. EUR 90bn, i.e. 0.9% of Eurozone's GDP. If we only take into account SME ABS not retained by banks for repo purposes we end up with a total stock of just EUR 10bn, i.e., 0.1% of Eurozone's GDP.


The numbers are absolutely accurate. And irrelevant. Who said that the ECB will only buy existing SME ABS?


Here is Thursday's ECB statement announcing the launch of the ABS programme:


"The Eurosystem will purchase a broad portfolio of simple and transparent asset-backed securities (ABSs) with underlying assets consisting of claims against the euro area non-financial private sector under an ABS purchase programme (ABSPP). This reflects the role of the ABS market in facilitating new credit flows to the economy and follows the intensification of preparatory work on this matter, as decided by the Governing Council in June."

There is no reference to "only existing" ABS. And during the Q&A session of ECB's press conference, Mario Draghi had this to say (note: underscoring is my own):


"Question: I have two questions. The first is on the purchase programmes that you announced. Do you have more details of what kind of ABS you are planning to buy? Mortgage, residential mortgage, just to SMEs?
Draghi: The purchase of ABS will involve both newly created and existing ABS and would also include the real estate, the RMBS, real estate ABS. It would also include a fairly wide range of ABS containing loans to the real economy."

The fact that ECB's purchase programme includes "newly created" ABS changes everything. It means that banks:
(i) Can structure ABS having existing loans to corporates as underlying and sell them to the ECB
(ii) Can make new loans to corporates (using ECB's cheap financing provided via TLTRO - targeted longer-term refinancing operations), repackage them as ABS and then sell these to the ECB (with the proceeds used to repay the TLTROs)

This is a sea-changing event. For at least 3 reasons:

1. The ECB will be the facto lending money almost directly to Eurozone's private corporate sector,  including SMEs. The banks will be simply unavoidable intermediaries in the process with corporate credit risk being fully transferred to the ECB (the ECB cannot by law lend directly to coporates having to use the banks as a conduit)

2. Banks can deleverage by transferring existing corporate loans to the ECB by repackaging them into ABS (without any negative impact on their P&L as a way will surely be found to transfer the loans to the ECB at the value they are accounted for in banks' balance sheets)

3. Banks can make some extra profits with no additional consumption of capital by conceding new loans to corporates and then repackage and transfer them as ABS to the ECB (first the banks make money via the interest rate differential between corporate loans and TLTROs; once the loans are repackaged into ABS and sold to the ECB, banks get rid of the credit risk and make money via the small differential between interests paid on individual corporate loans and slightly lower interests paid on corporate ABS due to the lower risk of a portfolio of individual corporate loans vs. the average individual loan contained in that portfolio). Thus improving their P&L, increasing retained earnings and capital buffers

How big will ABS PP's impact be? Mario Draghi mentioned that as a result of the programmes announced on Thursday, ECB's balance sheet should increase by EUR 1 trillion, 10% of Eurozone's GDP. Given that ABS and TLTRO are the facto linked (ECB's balance sheet increases with the concession of the later, which are then substituted by the former), the only question is how the EUR 1 trn will be split among ABS and covered bonds, for which a purchase programme was also announced on Thursday.

Assuming that
- 75% of the EUR 1 trn will be linked to ABS
- Eurozone's private sector corporate debt held by the banking sector is around EUR 7 trn (aprox. 80% of the total private sector corporate debt)
- SMEs account for approx. 50% of total Eurozone corporate bank loans
- the Eurozone peripheral countries (Italy, Spain, Portugal, Greece, Ireland) account for roughly 30% of this total and the main focus will be to unblock credit flows to these countries' SMEs

it follows that ECB's ABS programme could have an impact equivalent to
- approx. 11% of total existing bank loans to Eurozone corporates
- approx. 35% of total existing bank loans to Eurozone periphery corporates
- approx. 70% of total existing bank loans to Eurozone periphery SMEs

We can obviously discuss the assumptions just made and come up with different numbers, but the conclusion will stay the same: ECB's ABS purchase programme is hardly going to be just a bit of noise.

If we take into account that a public Eur 300bn investment programme (3% of Eurozone's GDP) is likely to be implemented by the European Union at the initiative of the new Juncker Commission, there is more than a fairly good chance that EU's economic growth will start to surprise on the upside in 2015. And if the investment programme is well targeted, i.e. investments in areas with a positive impact on the economy's supply side, rising its growth potential (needed infrastructure improvements, education & training, R&D), the effects will actually be more than just short-term GDP growth cosmetics in the best spirit of "Hollywood economics".

Having said this, will Draghinomics (and a bit Junckernomics) will be sufficient to definitely overcome Eurozone's financial and economic malaise? No.

Taken as a whole the Eurozone is in pretty decent shape. The problem is the asymmetry in competitiveness between centre and periphery. This can however only be solved by doing structural reforms in the periphery with the aim to attract massive amounts of foreign direct investment (FDI) to broaden the peripheral countries' production and export basis and thus solve their chronic and unsustainable current account deficits (especially true for Portugal, Spain, Greece).

Will political leaders take advantage of the 2-3 years time that Mario Draghi is buying them? No idea. The only think that is clear is that tracking their "structural reforms performance" will be easy as it just requires to monitor three variables: FDI investment to build new production capacity in the periphery (portfolio flows to buy existing assets don't count), exports, current account balance.

In the meantime, enjoy Super Mario's party. It will be a spectacular one.

Friday 1 August 2014

Europe and China: economics is not a zero-sum game

Let's start with the pessimistic view: China'a continuing economic rise is going to destroy European living standards. In 50 years, the European Union, and especially the Eurozone (if it still exists at all) will be a nice museum to visit. At best.

China's ascendancy in the world stage can be best captured by its export performance over the past two decades.....
      Source: WTO

All looking very dramatic, indeed. All surely very disruptive for Europe.

But also all very one-sided. The other side of the story is told by looking at China's imports evolution in 1990-2013.......
      Source: WTO

.....and the EU's and Eurozone's current account balances....
      Source: IMF

Putting words to pictures (all numbers in nominal USD):

Yes, China's exports multiplied by a factor of 36 (thirty six) from 1990 to 2013. China was not among the world's 15 major export nations in 1990. It is the number 1 export nation now.

The other, often overlooked side of the picture shows that China's imports multiplied by a factor of 37 (thirty seven) from 1990 to 2013. China was not among the world's 15 major import nations in 1990. It is the number 2 import nation now (after the US).

More importantly, the EU's current account has been well balanced throughout the whole period. In fact, and to be precise, the current account balance improved between 1990 and 2013: from -0.7% of EU's GDP in 1990 to +1.9% now. An improvement of 2.6% of GDP! Read slowly, please: it i-m-p-r-o-v-e-d while China was amidst its already legendary and seemingly unstoppable economic rise!

On top of it, the Eurozone looks even better than the whole of the European Union: in the seventeen year period from 1997 (2 years before the creation of the Euro) to 2013 it only registered a current account deficit in two years (2000 and 2008) and in both cases accounting for less than 1% of GDP. In 2013, the Eurozone achieved its largest ever current account surplus: 2.9% of GDP.

Now that we have the whole picture, things look everything but dramatic, don't they? As a whole, the European Union - and especially the "ill-and-at-some-point-certain-to-collapse" Eurozone - is and has always been a highly competitive economy. And a massive overall beneficiary from China's economic rise over the past 2 decades.

Is this surprising? It can only be a surprise if we think that economics is a zero-sum game - for one party to win another has to lose by the same amount - focus on economic losses and overlook economic gains as well as history. After the second world war, Germany and Japan were completely destroyed. The US was the world's absolute economic super-power. But surely everyone agrees today that Germany's and Japan's economic rise in post-WWII was good for both countries, for the world in general and for....the US.

Obviously, the German and Japanese economic rise led to disruptions of some US industrial sectors: where is the US automotive industry today vs. 1950? The streets of New York are packed with Mercedes, BMWs, Audis, Toyotas. Where are the Kodak cameras? Overtaken by Canon and Sony digital technology. Oh dear, oh dear. But the rise in German and Japanese living standards also led to massive consumption of US products in both countries. How many Germans don't have Microsoft software installed on their PCs and don't use Google as their search engine? How many Japanese don't have Intel inside their PC's, own some kind of Apple device and watch Hollywood movies?

The regional reallocation of resources between industries among the three countries has made their citizens better off and much wealthier than they were 60 years ago.

Why should it be different for China vs. Europe (and vs. rest of the world)? China started to open up and integrate into the world economy in 1979, in the wake of Deng Xiaoping's reforms. Becoming the largest exporter in the world, as China is now, is the beginning of normality. Abnormal was that the largest country in the world, accounting for 20% of the world's population, was not (even close) among the world's top-3 largest exporters for well over two centuries. Nor (even close) among the world's top-3 importers.

It's not possible to stress it enough: the fact that China is now the world's second largest import nation is absolute normality. And so is as well that it will become the largest global importer over the next 10-15 years: as a country becomes wealthier, it will import more goods and services from abroad. Obviously, to become wealthier China had and has to continue to develop globally competitive industries and companies, which disrupted and will continue to disrupt existing industries and companies in other countries. But other industries and companies from third countries will benefit from the higher demand for their products resulting from Chinese citizens' higher purchasing power. With higher purchasing power, Chinese citizens will buy more Mercedes and BMWs, Burberry, Louis Vuitton and Prada products, Geox and Camper shoes, Parmeggiano and Fuet, travel more abroad. And visit more European museums.

The European Union's problem is everything but overall lack of competitiveness and economic weakness. The problem is the economic asymmetry among its member countries: some produce many goods and services that the Chinese want to have and can't replicate, others produce few. The fact that China helped to expose the asymmetry is painful for the weak countries in the short-term. However, it creates a positive pressure for change that will lead them to have stronger and more well diversified economies in the future. Able to ensure higher living standards for their citizens. And building a more well diversified economy and stronger export basis means something as "simple" as implementing reforms to attract massive amounts of foreign direct investment (FDI). Why shouldn't Siemens, e.g., carry out R&D activities and set up high-tech production facilities in Portugal, Spain or Greece instead of Germany if the conditions are right?

With a well established democratic regime, rule of law and strong institutions, top-quality infrastructure, cultural diversity with a strong common basis, the planet's highest levels and most homogeneous distribution of human capital - not to mention a very often underestimated, overlooked and misperceived solidarity among its member countries to smooth out asymmetrical economic turbulences - the European Union will be much more than a nice museum to visit in 50 years time.

Being currently underestimated and underrated just makes the EU an even more attractive place to be. Opportunities abound. Seize them!

Monday 9 June 2014

ECB goes unconventional: Mr. Draghi is the Super Mario of problem framing

Mario Draghi did it again: negative ECB deposit facility rate (-0.1%); EUR 400bn targeted long-term refinancing operations (TLTRO) for private sector non-mortgage loans; stop sterilisation of government bond purchases done as part of the bank's Securities Markets Programme (SMP); potential future acquisition of non-financial private sector asset-backed securities (ABS). The announcement that more unconventional measures are likely to come "Are we finished? The answer is no, we aren't finished here. If need be, within our mandate, we aren't finished here" (Draghi dixit)

(For more details click here)

The official version is that these measures are directed at fighting the risk of deflation in the Eurozone. Is that really all that is being targeted? Is that really all that could even be targeted even if the sole goal were to fight the risk of deflation?

Let's put things in perspective: with the potential exception of the ABS bit, none of the announced measures will be effective in fighting deflation without a healthy and properly working banking system able to act as a transmission mechanism of ECB's (unconventional) monetary policy. However, currently the Eurozone's banking system is to a large extend under-capitalised. And therefore unable to act as "the" transmission mechanism. No matter how unconventional ECB's policy measures may be.

A proper recapitalisation of the system will take time to be fully achieved and to be done smoothly requires supportive equity markets:

- The results of the Asset Quality Review (AQR) exercise currently under way will be released in November 2014. Eurozone banks with capital shortfalls will then have 6 to 9 months to recapitalise themselves, i.e., till May to August 2015.

- Recaps should be mainly done via capital increases in the market place

- But private investors will only provide the financing if equity market's are booming and the sentiment is positive

Mario Draghi is surely aware of this. And therefore knows that it has to do "whatever it takes" to support the currently positive momentum in financial markets in general and equity markets in particular. This is what the measures announced last Thursday (5 June) have ultimately to achieve to be successful in fighting deflation.

In addition, it is not really desirable that financial markets start to collapse shortly after the Eurozone bank recaps are concluded. Banks would have to start to write off some of their then overvalued assets again and we would be back to square one. On top of it, the Bank Recovery and Resolution Directive (BRRD) with full bail-in mechanism - potentially going beyond equity and subordinated debt - will enter into force in January 2016. Not really a good time to see the markets roll over.

Putting all this bits and pieces together gives us a broader picture of what is going on, with the risk of deflation occupying just a corner area of the whole picture. And the conclusion can only be that Mario Draghi will keep doing whatever it takes to keep investors in Eurozone's financial markets happy and cheerful until way into 2016.

Given that deflation in at least the non-tradable sectors is set to remain in place in the Eurozone periphery, following the adjustment in local nominal salaries (never mind that this will actually increase consumers purchasing power and lead to a rebound in consumption rather than a deferral of it in these countries), inflation is to remain very low in the whole of the Euro area over the entire period. Mr. Draghi can therefore continue to frame the problem he is facing as one of pure deflation. It is academically elegant, politically convenient and easier to be accepted by Bundesbank hawks. And thus able to gain unanimous support for additional unconventional policy measures. Nothing really new here: support for an action is more readily won by a skilful and attractive framing of the problem at stake than of the action intended to solve it.

Will ECB's interventionism create distortions in financial markets? It surely will. Misallocation of capital? No doubt. An adverse impact on long-term productivity and economic growth? Most likely. Will the boom eventually end in a bust? Yes - gravity in economics as in finance does exist.

Should you fight Mario Draghi now? No. Over the next 18 to 24 months Mario Draghi will be Super Mario. And you should never fight a super-hero at the top of his game. Just enjoy his skill and make the best of it.

Saturday 31 May 2014

European Union: the 2-in-1 Nobel Prize

We are in Europe in 1945. The second world war just ended. And the question in many peoples' minds is: since, let's say, the beginning of the renaissance in the XV century, how many 50-year periods of peace did we have in Europe? How many 25-year periods?

The answers are: zero. And zero.

How comes that the highly civilized Europe is constantly at war? How can we stop the recurrent suffering, destruction and losses?

The answer to the last question was a visionary strategy:

1. Create a strong economic interdependence between the European countries and give them free access to each others markets, i.e., free movement of goods & services and capital within Europe

2. Create the conditions for ordinary Europeans to get to know and regularly interact with each other, i.e., allow for free movement of people and labour within Europe

3. Allow membership to the "club" only to fully democratic countries and create supra-national decision making bodies on which all member-countries are represented and have veto rights on strategic decisions

The strategy was compelling because it was based on very sound logic:

a) By creating a large common European market the economic incentives for territorial expansion and disputes, which are at the origin of all wars - even when the official motives and "selling points" are others - were eliminated. Why start a war with a neighbouring country to expand your internal market and have access to additional resources if you have free access to that market and resources, under the same rules and conditions that apply in your original home market anyway? With a large common market, the national economic elites stopped having any kind of incentive to finance wars. Why would they be willing to finance a war with a neighbouring country when they have subsidiary companies, suppliers and clients in that country - on whom they depend on and with whom they have very close relationships - which are subject to the same rules and regulation as the ones applying in the home country? "Lebensraum"-type nonsense arguments stopped having any persuasive power to the economic elite. And without the backing of an important part of the economic elite, the chances of a country going to war are slim

b) By creating the conditions and incentives for ordinary Europeans from different nationalities to interact and get to know each other better, by travelling to, studying and working in different countries, effectively what was being created were the conditions for European citizens to realise, based on personal experience, that there is much more that unities than separates them. Once this is achieved, and cross-country personal friendships exist, the chances of a significant part of the general population supporting a war against a neighbouring country disappear

c) By imposing that all member countries of the "club" were democracies, a compliance of political decisions with the populations majority view was made more likely. By creating supra-national decision-making bodies, continuous interaction, debate and collaboration between national governments became mandatory. Interaction, debate and collaboration identify common interests, solve differences and create trust. Trust - the key to avoid wars: you will not go to war with someone you trust.

Not less important: by only allowing fully democratic countries into the "club", internal political stability in each member-country was massively enhanced. Military coups d'etat became an almost impossibility. For a coup d'etat to take place, its leaders must be able to deliver an improvement in living standards for significant parts of the population in the short-term - or at least a "realistic illusion" that an improvement can be delivered. Otherwise, the new regime will quickly collapse. Given that a coup d'etat would lead to a member country being expelled from the "club", and its economic / trading ties with its main economic partners cut-off, no short-term improvement or "illusion" of improvement could be delivered for a significant part of the population as a result of one. And the economic elites, highly integrated into the "club's" economic space, would be the first to suffer. No support from a significant part of the economic elite, no support from a significant part of the general population, means no coup d'etat.

Finally, a prosperous and peaceful "club" of sovereign states would act as an attracting force for countries living under dictatorships. And the hope of belonging to the "club" and enjoying its benefits provide an anchor of social stability in the transition phase to democracy.

The result of the visionary strategy as we all know was the construction of the European Union, kicked-off with the signature of the Treaty of Rome in 1957.

- How many wars did we have among European Union member states since 1945? Z-e-r-o.

- How many coups d'etat in European Union member states since 1945? Z-e-r-o.

- How can the peaceful transition in the former east European communist countries, now EU members, be explained - when there were so many from the former ruling communist elite set to lose their power and privileges - but for the expectation that the integration in the EU would open many new opportunities for everyone that more than offset the losses?

However you look at it, almost 70 years of peace among EU-member countries - something never experienced before - is indeed a spectacular achievement at all levels. And surely generated a massive economic "peace dividend". How much is it worth? To answer the question we just have to answer the following underlying questions: how much higher is today's EU's GDP (remember: GDP is an annual concept. Whatever the benefit, it occurs year after year after year) as a result of the EU

- having a much larger population vs. what it would have if recurrent wars had continued to happen?
- a healthier population?
- a better educated population?
- a longer working population?
- no destruction of infrastructure?
- more resources being channelled to education, R&D and leading to higher productivity?

Here a quick of the envelope calculation:

- Over 2% of European Union's member countries population was killed during the the first as well as second world war. Taking into account that the overwhelming majority of those killed was part of the labour force and assuming a labour force participation rate of 65%, this accounts for circa 3% of annual GDP

- Given that the vast majority of those who died were young adults and therefore the main source for future productivity enhancements and innovation, it is reasonable to add 50% to the 3%. This leaves us at 4.5% of GDP

- If we add those who suffered war injuries and became permanently (to a less or larger extend) handicapped, less productive and with a shorter working life, it is surely reasonable to double the 4.5% to 9%.

- If we add (i) the benefits of not having to regularly channel resources to rebuild destroyed infrastructure, care for the handicapped and have more of the available resources being channeled to education, R&D, productive investments, (ii) the benefits of a faster and more sustainable accumulation of human capital and (iii) the benefits of a long-term oriented mindset, stable institutional framework and investment projects that will only be pursued, and whose fruits can only be fully reaped, if regular recurrences of war are highly unlikely to occur, what will happen to the 9%? Will they double or triple?

In short: saying that the European Union's annual GDP is 20%-25% higher as a result of the "peace dividend" it created is a perfectly sound statement to make.

And finally: how much is a saved human life worth?

On the other side of the balance, how much does the EU generated "peace dividend" cost us? The answer is: the "monstrous" European Union budget accounts for 1% of European Union's annual GDP. Seriously. It's really just ONE percent! (By the way, the "infamous" Brussels- and Strasbourg-based EU bureaucrats' share of that is 6%, i.e., 0.06% of EU's GDP)

The conclusion of all this is therefore pretty straightforward: those who have criticised the Nobel committee for awarding the Peace Nobel Prize to the Europen Union in 2013 were right in doing so. The European Union should have been awarded two Nobel Prizes instead: Peace and Economics.



PS As an European Union citizen living in London, what can I say about masterpiece Nigel Farage (UKIP's leader)? As usual, my respect and admiration for British pragmatism and humour is endless: British people keep sending to the European parliament someone they never wanted to elect to their own national parliament. Well done - noisy troublemakers are always best dealt with by sending them away.

Sunday 11 May 2014

Piketty: right or wrong?

In his book "Capitalism in the Twenty-first Century", Thomas Piketty claims that capitalism has an embedded inequality feature. If not corrected by government intervention, a socially unsustainable level of inequality will be reached, putting not only democracy at risk but eventually leading to the collapse of capitalism.

Marx had argued something similar in the second half of the XIX century. He was proven wrong. Does it mean that Piketty is wrong as well?

He is wrong and right:

1. Piketty is wrong

His assumption that r > g, can't hold true in the long-run (note: r = return on capital; g = economic growth) unless the savings rate is zero and the capital stock stays constant over time (meaning: all income from both capital and labour would be spent on consumption), which in a society with a high concentration of wealth can't be the case - capital owners will save and reinvest part of their capital income leading to an increasing stock of capital.

Keeping in mind that GDP is the sum of the production factors' remuneration - remuneration of capital (including remuneration of land) and remuneration of labour - let's assume (an extreme example, but in-corrections are always easier to detect at the extremes) that

g = 0

and

r > g
(with part of the income from capital being saved and reinvested leading to a continuous increase in the stock of capital).

This would mean that the share of the remuneration of capital in GDP would increase steadily over time until it reached 100%, leading to a 100% unemployment rate in the long-run. Put differently: all the productivity gains - generated by the increase in the stock of capital (e.g. investment in technology) - would be passed entirely to the owners of capital, who would save and reinvest them and keep substituting labour with capital, people with robots, until there were no more people to be substituted (let's forget for an instance that capital can never fully substitute labour).

This is not possible.

Way before we reached "full unemployment", either

(A) a social revolt would take place and capital start to be massively taxed bringing r down and leading to r = g (with g increasing above 0 as the additional taxes would be transferred directly or indirectly to labour leading to an increase in private consumption, aggregate demand and GDP. I.e. taxation would pass part of the productivity gains to labour)

or

(B) the productivity gains would have to be directly passed to a large extent to labour. Meaning: reduced working hours / reduced working week (e.g. 4 day work week) / more holidays for employees while keeping their salaries untouched. This would keep the share of the remuneration of labour in GDP constant and, obviously, the share of the remuneration of capital in GDP constant as well. As GDP remained constant (g=0), so would the total absolute remuneration of capital. But as r > g implies an increase in the stock of capital (part of the remuneration of capital is saved), this would result in a decrease of r until it converged progressively to g.

Yes, the law of diminishing marginal returns is like gravity: we may not notice it, but it does exist.


2. Piketty is right

Given that

i) in the long-run we are all death

ii) (A) is surely not a scenario we want to go through while alive

iii) (B) won't happen easily and fast enough on its own

we can't sit on our hands and wait that g converges to r. Otherwise, (A) will happen. And rightly so.

So, the government must act. By taxing income above USD 500k at 80%? No, the Laffer curve with income tax rates above 50% stops being Hollywood fiction to become reality, i.e., bad for growth. With an up to 10% global wealth tax? Not really a good idea. To start with, because it would never be complied with on a global scale.

What to do then? This:

1. Broaden the ownership of capital via government top-ups of pension funds and savings accounts

2. Reform the tax system to one more tilted towards a very progressive income tax instead of indirect taxation to avoid that a large, socially disruptive inequality develops in the first place.

3. More public spending on high quality education and R&D. Education is the best tool to ensure social mobility. Education and R&D combined an effective way to generate sustainable economic growth.

4. Limit the leverage in the financial system. Big capital owners are the ones that have access to large scale financing as they have the resources to put up as collateral. Nothing wrong with this, as long as the financing is used for productivity enhancing activities. However, to a large extend that's not the case and the financing ends up being used for highly leveraged, highly risky financial bets with limited positive impact on the economy's overall productivity. Then again: even this would be perfectly legitimate if when the bets went wrong - pushing their returns over the entire economic cycle down to mediocre levels - the ones pursuing them were held accountable for their mistakes. It would reduce their willingness to pursue them in the first place. Sadly however, and as we all know, when large scale systemic accidents occur, the taxpayer foots the bill - not the ones that freely took the decision to pursue the bets. Thus, creating the incentives for a large scale mis-allocation of resources in the first place. By forcing banks to have much higher equity buffers we would limit the financial leverage in the system and end up with a financial sector both more resilient as well as a more efficient allocator of financial resources to the economy. Productivity would benefit. Sustainable economic growth would be higher and so would be living standards. Socially disruptive inequality contained.

5. Making sure that a fair share of productivity gains is transferred to labour. Besides being able to pursue other interest outside work from which the whole community benefits (any hidden Shakespeares or Picassos out there?), employees with more leisure time and cash in their pockets are a nice source of consumption and aggregate demand. And therefore a positive contribution to g, making the convergence r = g happen at a higher level. And everyone happy.

6. Remember that population aging is a demographic variable. But pension age is not - it is a political one. Raising the pension age is unavoidable if our developed world welfare systems are to remain sustainable. With part of the productivity gains being transferred to labour, it will be easier to persuade employees to accept later retirement: why not work 4 days a week until 75 years of age instead of working 5 days a week until 65? The alternative is to continue to retire at 65 and transfer all the productivity gains, via taxation, to the "young" pensioners to keep the welfare system afloat. You choose.

By the way, transfer of productivity gains to labour and related higher employee remuneration, reduced working hours and increased leisure is what happened since the XIX century in the developed world. It created a broad middle class and proved Marx's prediction of capitalism's collapse wrong.

Piketty may not be right in everything he says, but the inequality debate and its impact on social stability and consequently on sustainable economic growth and general living standards was overdue. Once we understand that the market does, in general, a great job in allocating scarce resources efficiently and is therefore a fantastic wealth creation mechanism, but that it is not able to ensure on its own a socially sustainable distribution of the wealth created putting thus at risk its very and precious existence, the advise can only be one inspired by Henry Ford:

Capitalists of the developed world, unite! Let's bring on the 4-day working week and prove Marx wrong again.


PS Why Henry Ford is a true master of capitalism and source of inspiration:
http://www.history.com/this-day-in-history/ford-factory-workers-get-40-hour-week

Wednesday 30 April 2014

Greece - please repeat all together now: E-X-P-O-R-T-S!

Greece achieved a (better than expected) primary budget surplus, accounting for 0.8% of GDP in 2013. The current account is balanced. And April 2014 marked the return of the Greek sovereign to international financial markets with the issuance of an almost 7x over-subscribed 5-year EUR 3bn bond (4.95% yield). Not bad. Is all fine and dandy now?

At the root of Greece's problems was its high external debt and consequent dependency from international financing. The only way to effectively solve an external debt problem in a sustainable way - i.e., avoiding its recurrence a few years down the road after an implicit or explicit debt restructuring - is by improving competitiveness and turning continuous current account deficits into continuous current account surpluses or at least into a sustainably balanced current account.

The improvement in the Greek current account has been remarkable. No doubt about it:

      Source: IMF


Similarly to the other GIPS, the adjustment in the current account couldn't have taken place without a very significant downward adjustment in imports.....

      Source: IMF

However, the contribution of the Greek export sector to the current account adjustment has been much more subdued than in the case of other GIPS......

     Source: IMF

And the question is: how can a country that underwent a massive reduction in unit labour costs (ULC) over the past 5 years......


     Source: Eurostat, ECB, Ameco, Tortus Capital

......bringing them down to pre-Euro levels.......


     Source: OECD

....have had such a dismal export performance?

The answer can only be that either (i) the structural reforms agreed with the Troika have not been properly implemented at the micro-level or (ii) we are dealing with a economic abnormality that a process of reversion to the mean will correct over the next 24 months.

If the latter holds true, prepare yourself for a cheerful upside surprise in Greek export-led economic growth over the next 2 years. Investors in general, and equity investors in particular, will enjoy many happy days over the next 18-24 months. And beyond.

If the former proves to be the correct explanation, as soon as the economy starts to grow again - and it doesn't need to grow much - a rebound in imports will follow and current account deficits return. Five years of austerity and social unrest would have constituted an inglorious effort. Greece's imbalances much more serious and deeply ingrained than thought. And international investors - even taking into account that 85% of the public debt is held by the Troika - forced to review their positions in the country. Under this scenario, they will most likely still enjoy 18-24 months of happy Greek investment return days - driven by further Troika held public debt restructuring via maturity extensions and lowering of interest rates. But not beyond.

So, the message for investors in Greece is straightforward: focus on the evolution of exports and inflows of foreign direct investment (FDI) - the key driver to enlarge and broaden the country's export basis - over the next 18-24 months. All the rest are details.

Monday 17 March 2014

China: don't be fooled by the availability bias

Will the Chinese credit bubble, much of it reliant on shadow banking financing, lead to a major financial crisis in the country and drag down the global economy?

China is well known for its opaque statistical data. This renders a detailed and reliable assessment of the country's credit bubble basically impossible.

However, sometimes there are situations where by just keeping things simple, focusing on the big picture and quantifying it, we are able to reach robust enough conclusions to spare us from having to spend ages delving into detail. China's credit bubble is one of these situations.

There are many thing we don't know about China. And two we know for sure:

1. China has been running continuous current account surpluses for the past 20 years......
.....with the country's foreign exchange reserves peaking at USD 3.8 trillion in December 2013 (approximately 45% of GDP). This means that the Chinese economy is not dependent on external financing to pay for its imports (including raw materials, intermediate and capital goods). A sudden stop cannot occur (meaning: no danger of disruptions in Chinese production, demand and international supply chains). Unless a massive flight of capital from China were to take place.

2. China macroeconomic framework doesn't allow for free movements of capital. The capital account is closed. With a closed capital account there can be no massive flight of capital out of the country. So, a sudden stop cannot occur. Really.

The Chinese government has therefore all the resources needed to avoid a massive financial crisis. Or putting it differently: for a devastating financial crisis in China to occur one has to assume that the Chinese government (a) is not aware that one can occur or (b) is aware that it can occur, but not willing to avoid it via a bail-out of the financial system when, and if, push comes to shove.

Neither (a) nor (b) apply. The Chinese authorities are very aware and vigilant of the excesses in the financial system as their recent public statements show. And they will not risk a major financial crisis and the resulting potential social and political tensions. They may not be happy bailing out large parts of their financial system. They may even think that bail-ins and debt-to-equity swaps would be a more effective way to deal with the problem on a longer-term perspective. And they are certainly aware that bailing-out large parts of the financial system is de facto protecting past and  incentivising future misallocation of resources in the economy, which will unavoidably impact negatively the economy's long-term growth potential. But in the end they will have to act in a way consistent with the the communist party's dominant political objectives. And these happen to be economic development and keeping social and political stability at all time. It follows that massive intervention and bail-outs, if needed, will occur.

Why then do many of us in the West tend to think that a financial crisis is likely to occur in China? Human behavioural biases are at work: availability bias / representativeness heuristics, i.e., recent large scale events tend to feature predominantly in our memory and shape our perception of the world. Having gone through the largest financial crisis of our lifetime, we tend to focus on apparently similar imbalances to the ones that led to "our" financial crisis, ignore the differences (e.g. the FED's disregard for the dangers of sub-prime debt vs. the Chinese authorities' focus on the dangers of their credit bubble) and over-extrapolate. The result is that we are likely going to predict 20 out of the next 2 financial crisis.

Am I simplifying too much? I don't think so. And recommend that you keep it simple: if markets were to come down by 15%-20% as a result of a supposed Chinese financial crisis triggered panic, please remember Warren Buffett and "be fearful when others are greedy and greedy when others are fearful".

Monday 10 February 2014

Cry for me Argentina?

Will emerging markets' current economic crisis lead to a fully fledged currency crisis, which in turn triggers an out-of-control inflation (hyperinflation) in EM countries?

No. With one possible exception: Argentina.

Once you have a severe current account crisis, the options to overcome it are:

1. A draconian and swift contraction in domestic demand via a brutal fiscal adjustment accompanied by a currency devaluation

2. A more moderate multi-period contraction in domestic demand via a moderate multi-period fiscal adjustment accompanied by a softer currency devaluation. This requires external support (i.e. IMF) to finance the (shrinking) current account deficit during the period of adjustment

3. A miraculous swing of the current account deficit into surplus as a result of a rise in exports

Given that in the Argentinean case (1) will not happen for internal political reasons and (2) is out of discussion as a result of Argentine's 2001 default and the country being at odds with all major international financial institutions, either an economic miracle happens or a fully fledged currency crisis and inflation spiral will ensue at some point in 2014.

To fully understand why, you don't need me. All you need to do is to read the 1990 classic paper about "macroeconomic populism" from the great Rudiger Dornbusch

Enjoy!

Friday 24 January 2014

Greece: the best of the GIPS?

With a public debt to GDP ratio of 175% (public debt around Eur 320bn), Greece's debt burden is unsustainable. A debt restructuring unavoidable.

Given that (i) the Troika (EU, ECB, IMF) is not willing to restructure Greek debt and (ii) Greece will not be able to achieve any reasonable economic growth under such a heavy debt burden, social and political turmoil is unavoidable. The left-wing Syriza party, led by Alexis Tsipras, will win the next early general elections - taking place in 2015, the latest -, force a debt restructuring, impose capital controls, nationalise the entire banking system and lead Greece out of the Euro. Private investors, starting with Greek government bondholders, will suffer heavy losses. But leaving the Euro is the right thing to do: Greece has no chance to regain its competitiveness staying in the Eurozone. The Greek exit in turn will trigger Portugal and Spain's exit from the Euro. Possibly even Italy's. It will mark the beginning of the end of the Euro project.

This, in short, is the prevalent view among many economists, investors, leading newspapers and opinion makers. However, sometimes perception and reality are far, far apart. This is one of those notable occasions. This is why:

1. The Greek public debt burden is undoubtedly very high. But 85% of it is held by the Troika: EU, 65%; ECB, 10%; IMF, 10%. Meaning: a debt restructuring doesn't require any private sector involvement. The debt restructuring can be borne by official creditors alone.

2. There is no incentive to involve the private sector in a public debt restructuring. Why scare off private investors - who are so very much needed for a jump in investment, structural change in Greek's productive structure (via FDI) and economic growth - when (i) they only hold 15% of the total Greek public debt (ii) some of them have just put Greece back on their radar screen, (iii) the first Greek public debt restructuring back in 2011 was borne by private investors and (iv) it is much easier to sit at a table and negotiate with three creditors (EU, ECB and IMF) than with hundreds of them (private investors). Therefore, even if Syriza wins the next general elections don't expect any losses for private investors in Greek debt. Alexis Tsipras may be a populist politician, but he is not mad. He knows too well that foreign investment (and especially FDI) is needed to turn the Greek economy around and create the foundations for sustainable economic growth.

3. The 65% of public debt held by the EU had initially (2010) a 7-year maturity. It paid an interest rate of 3M Euribor +5.5%. Since then maturities have been extended and interest rates cut, leading to the following figures at the end of December 2013:

- The debt maturity is 31 years

- The interest rate on 15% out of the 65% (EU bilateral loans - Greek loan facility (GLF) - as the EU rescue fund EFSF / EFSM / ESM was not yet in place in 2010) is 3M Euribor + 0.5%

- The interest rate on the remaining 50% out of the 65% is 3M Euribor + 1.5%. More importantly, interest payments on these loans (already conceded by the EFSF) were deferred for 10 years. No interest payments are due until November 2022

Sounds good? It gets even better: in November 2012, the EU agreed to transfer every year to the Greek government the profits made by the ECB with its securities market programme (SMP) accruing to the Greek central bank. In 2013, this amounted to Eur 1.5bn. The total interest payments to the Troika were Eur 1.7bn (less than 1% of Greek GDP)

4. Currently, total interest payments on Greek public debt account (including the deferred interest payments on EFSF loans) for 3.5% of the country's GDP. This compares with 2% for Germany; 3.2% for Spain; 4.1% for Portugal; 4.3% for Ireland; 5.2% for Italy.

By the way, did the Euro make everything worse? No. At the end of 1998 (just before the Euro was launched), Greek interest payments on public debt accounted for 7.4% of GDP. For Italy, the figure was 6.1%; Portugal, 3.8%; Spain, 3.3%; Ireland, 2.2%. Except for Ireland, the lower interest rates post-Euro (and generous bail-out financing terms for Greece, Portugal and Ireland) more than offset the currently (much) higher levels of public debt.

In short: contrary to common wisdom it is not true that the Troika, led by the EU, is not willing to restructure Greece's public debt. A soft and silent Greek public debt restructuring has been under way for the past 2 years. Simply neither the EU (and especially Germany) nor Greece have been advertising it very loudly for obvious political reasons. But being silent doesn't mean being non-existent.

Is there anything missing for the Greek debt restructuring to be completed? Maybe. Namely:

a) Extending the maturities of ECB held bonds and IMF loans to over 30 years and reduce interest rates to 3M Euribor + 50bps (GLF terms) on all debt held by the Troika? No problem.

The IMF wants to get out of Greece and its money back at the end of 2016. Mr. Schäuble, the German finance minister, said during the German election campaign in the summer 2013, that Greece would need a third and last rescue package of Eur 50bn to Eur 60bn by the end of 2016. The IMF loans and ECB held bonds amount on aggregate to roughly Eur 60bn. What a coincidence, isn't it?

With the ESM replacing the IMF and ECB as creditor, consider the debt maturity extension and lowering of interest rates to 3M Euribor + 50bps (on the entire official sector held Greek public debt) a done deal. Obviously all this will be made conditional to the country continuing to implement the famous structural reforms. And obviously with the Greek government trying to soften down conditionality as much as possible while the EU trying to keep the pressure high at all times. But in the end an agreement will be reached. As usual.*

b) Extending debt maturities to 50 years for a sustainable level of public debt to be achieved? Doable, if needed.

Or is it reasonable to expect that after having extended debt maturities from 7 to over 30 years over the past 2 years, and all the effort made to stabilize the financial situation in Greece and the EU periphery, the EU will not concede Greece such a debt extension if needed? The answer can only be a resounding "no".

And now the important question: what will be the impact of (i) extending maturities to 30 years on all Greek public debt held by the Troika (remember: this means that none of this debt has to be refinanced for 30 years) and (ii) lower interest rates to a level such that Greece will be able to generate a primary surplus to pay the interests on all its public debt (held by the Troika and private investors)?

- Assuming a nominal annual growth rate of 4% over a 30 year period (30 years is a long, long time) - and with private sector held debt as a % of GDP remaining constant - Greek public debt would reach 70% of GDP by 2043

- In case of a debt maturity extension to 50 years, Greek public debt as a % of GDP would reach 45% in 2063

We can discuss all these assumptions and results. But that would be missing the point of the whole exercise. The point is to show that (i) by eliminating the refinancing needs / refinancing risk on public debt held by the official sector for 30 (or 50) years and (ii) continuing to lower interest rates to enable Greece to fully cover its interest payments with a modest primary public budget surplus, the Troika (read EU) is effectively restructuring slowly, surely and silently Greece's public debt.

The most interesting of all is that this gigantic public debt restructuring is about to make the country the best GIPS in terms of balance sheet quality. Sounds lunacy? Can't after all the same soft and silent debt restructuring strategy be followed for other countries, like Portugal, Ireland and Spain?

Yes and no. It can be done. It will be done. However, the impact will be more limited: Portugal's public debt is around 120% of GDP, but "just" 45% of it is held by the Troika; for Ireland's the numbers are 105% and 40%, respectively; for Spain 90% and less than 5%.

More importantly, Greece's comparative advantage doesn't lie on its public sector balance sheet. The key to understand why Greece is about to become the GIPS best quality balance sheet is to look at countries' private debt levels. The following chart makes things clear (note: the data is from Dec 2010, but no meaningful changes occurred in private debt levels. Only in public debt, which increased in all depicted countries. Reason for which I relieved myself from the pain of updating the chart with the most recent BIS data):

      Source: BIS / Casey Research

No, there is no mistake in the chart. And no, it's not an illusion. Your eye-sight is just doing fine: Greece is the EU country with the lowest level of private debt (household and corporate) as a % of GDP. Lower than Italy. Lower than Austria. Lower than Germany. With the public debt restructuring under way, Greece is about to become the EU country with the cleanest aggregate balance sheet (public + private). Surprise, surprise.

What about external competitiveness? Isn't Greece's lack of competitiveness at the root of its debt problems? Yes, it is. And doesn't this mean that an Euro exit is the only realistic way for the loss of competitiveness to be restored? No, it doesn't.

The loss of competitiveness has in fact been restored over the past three years. Look for yourself to what happened to Greek unit labour costs....

      Source: OECD

....and to put Greece's unit labour costs (ULC) evolution in perspective, here are two more charts:

      Source: Eurostat, ECB, Ameco, Tortus Capital

      Source: Eurostat, ECB, Ameco, Tortus Capital

Not bad at all, isn't it? And yes, Greece is now (end 2013) running a small current account surplus. Furthermore, with more than 2/3 of the Greek public supporting the Euro, exiting the Eurozone is definitely not an option any Greek politician is going to pursue.

Finally, could Mr. Tsipras force a debt haircut if he comes to power? Now that Greece is running a current account surplus - and not dependent on external financing anymore to pay for its imports - as well as a primary public budget surplus, he certainly could declare default and force a restructuring of the Troika (and especially EU) loans. From a pure financial point of view, it wouldn't make much sense: even if he obtained a 50% haircut on the EU held debt, and Greece financed itself in the market at a 4% interest rate for 10-year maturities afterwards, the Greek government would pay more in interests than it is paying now (and as much as it would pay without the 10-year interest deferral on EFSF loans). From a political point of view it might however be an attractive option: he would be deemed the national hero that liberated the Greek people from their suffocating debt burden.

Then again, in practical economic terms an haircut would only make visible and loud what is currently hidden and silent: a massive debt relief for the Greek government is taking place. Besides, will prime-minster Samaras, after taking all the blame for the short-term pain of structural reforms, sit on his hands and see how Mr. Tsipras takes the praise for a debt restructuring that is already under way? Certainly not. Mr. Samaras will more than ever put pressure on the EU for an even more comprehensive and faster debt reduction via further debt extensions and lower interest rates. And the EU will surely prefer to deal with a government led by Mr. Samaras than one led by Mr. Tsipras. So, expect more debt relief to happen sooner rather than later.

Today in Greece, reality is much better than perception. The EU/German strategy of keeping the pressure high, forcing structural reforms - well knowing that not all will be implemented - and in return restructure / forgive part of the public debt is just working fine.

And all this is very, very cool indeed.

--------------------
* Note: Greece ended 2013 with a small primary public budget surplus. However, a total annual public deficit (after interests) of approximately 3.5% of GDP (around Eur 6bn) is likely to remain in place for the next 2, 3 years. This could increase the size of the last rescue package flagged by Mr. Schäuble in the summer 2013 by Eur 15-20bn (or force the ECB to extend maturities and lower the coupons on its bonds to match the terms of the most favourable EU loans). After having lent c. Eur 200bn to Greece over the past 3 years, it will not be Eur 20bn that will make a deal derail.