“It’s impossible to agree with a German economist. They
don’t get it.” How often did we hear this kind of statement over the past five
years?
Implied is that Germans are so much detail obsessed that
they miss the big picture. To be fair, Germans are indeed obsessed with detail.
They are the engineering nation, aren’t they?
Then again, they are also a nation of philosophers, who
almost by definition are big picture thinkers. And when it comes to economics, philosophers
are indeed what German are. Big picture thinkers in search of sound economic
principles (not surprisingly, in Germany econometrics is normally not a
mandatory subject in an economics degree programme and the overall level of
mandatory math courses is quite shallow).
The German economic model itself is the result of a big
picture approach to problem solving. It goes like this: reality is far too
complex and unpredictable to be mathematically modelled with great detail. So,
let’s focus on what we know and put in place some principles that if followed
will guarantee the achievement of sustainable economic prosperity. The result
is the German economic principles trinity.
Principle one: a
fully independent central bank whose only mandate is price stability
Why? Because…..
….the only way to increase a country’s economic living
standards sustainably over time is by increasing productivity. The way to
increase productivity is by continuously investing in education, training on
the job, innovation and technology (increase a country’s human and physical
capital). How can we force companies to continuously re-invest part of their
profits in training, innovation, technology instead of paying out bigger
dividends to shareholders? By putting them continuously under competitive
pressure. How do we do that? By having a stable currency.
If we devalue whenever there is a loss of competitiveness
relative to foreign competitors, local companies won’t make a great effort in
investing in training, innovation and technology. Why should they? When in
trouble, they know that a currency devaluation will bail them out and restore
their competitiveness. However, if a regular currency devaluation is not an
option – and on top of it currency devaluations do happen regularly in
countries where some of their competitors are based – they know that the only chance
they have to remain competitive is by continuously investing in their human
capital and technology.
How can we make sure, that politicians do not resort to
regular currency devaluations? Simple: by ringfencing monetary policy from
their interference (politicians are not allowed to access the “printing press”).
This is achieved by creating a fully independent central bank, whose only
mandate is to keep price stability and thus a stable currency. In addition,
such a fully independent central bank will over time make the “promise” of a
stable currency credible by committing to it. This credibility will lead to
lower interest rates (with no risk of recurrent devaluations, international
investors will ask for an ever lower interest rate risk premium to lend money
to local issuers – government and corporates). Lower interest rates will reduce
the cost of financing for the local government and companies. Making in turn
massive investments in human and physical capital more feasible. Thus,
companies have the pressure to continuously invest in human capital &
technology and the financial means to do so.
In short, principle number one intents to set in motion a
virtuous sequence of events: fully independent central bank whose only mandate
is to keep price stability ---> stable currency---> put companies under
permanent high competitive pressure----> forcing them to permanent high investment
in human capital, innovation and technology ---> increase in productivity
----> sustainable increase in citizens’ living standards
Principle two: a balanced
current account (or a current account surplus)
How do we know if the country is staying internationally
competitive? By monitoring the current account balance. If the current account
is balanced or in surplus nothing needs to be done. Everything is under
control. If the current account swings consistently into deficit, something is
not working. Structural reforms are needed to improve the countries
competitiveness (think about Schroeder’s Agenda 2010)
Principle three:
solid & solvent public accounts at all time
No matter how well the economy is run, there will always be
recessions, unexpected disruptive events, negative external shocks that
adversely impact the economy. In such situations, decisive government intervention
is needed to stabilise it. In order for the government to be able to act
forcefully, and run large public deficits in times of economic crisis, it has
to have available fiscal space at inception of a crisis. It has to be solvent
and public debt low when the crisis hits. Putting it differently, to run large
deficits when the going gets tough, the government has to run a reasonably
balanced budget in good times.
Finally, principles two and three combined also mean that the
economic authorities don’t have to worry much about private debt levels. If the
current account is at least balanced and the government is running a small deficit
(in good times) it follows that the private sector (families and corporates) is
running a surplus. So, either it is not accumulating debt or the debt is backed
by assets denominated in the same currency as the debt - which makes dealing
with situation of overleverage, and its impact on the financial system, much
easier.
If you look at the Eurozone crisis from the perspective of
the German economic trinity principle, you quickly understand why Germans
insist so much on structural reforms in the peripheral countries. Since the
second world war, Spain, Portugal and Greece have run current account deficits
the vast majority of the time – making them dependent on external financing. Such
external imbalances will eventually trigger a “sudden stop” in international
financing and a financial crisis. They way out of this structural weakness is
to expand the countries’ export base. This in turn can only be realistically
achieved by attracting massive amounts of foreign direct investment. How to do
it? By doing structural reforms that make the countries’ attractive to foreign direct
investors (the Siemens, the Sanofis, the Googles, the deutsche Mittelstand
& Co of the world).
So the question is: should we waste our energy and intellect
in building ever more complex and elegant mathematical models instead of focusing
on what we know about economics and keep things simple? The German answer is “Nein”.
That’s surely not something so difficult to agree with, is it?
No comments:
Post a Comment